Rajat Nag is a distinguished policy leader and educator. A former Managing Director-General at the Asian Development Bank and Distinguished Fellow of the Emerging Markets Forum, he focuses on governance, public policy innovation, and institutional development in emerging economies.
Amogh Dev Rai:
I formally welcome you to SenseMaker once again. Itâs good to have this conversation, sir. Good afternoon and weâre meeting virtually after a long time. So, first and foremost, welcome back to SenseMaker. This is your third time as a speaker here.
Rajat Nag:
Thanks, Amogh. Glad to be here.
Amogh Dev Rai:
In no particular order, just to familiarise our readers and listenersâ
Youâve served as the Managing Director General of the Asian Development Bank (ADB) from 2006 to 2013, and youâve been part of the ADB and other international organisations before that. You got your undergraduate degree in engineering from the Indian Institute of Technology, Delhi then moved to Canada for your first Masterâs, and later, another Masterâs from the London School of Economics and Political Science. Youâve often mentioned that your interactions with one of your teachers Prof. Amartya Sen) there was pivotalâit made you shift from investment banking to the world of international development.
Since then, youâve remained deeply engaged with international development. Your alma mater in Canada, University of Sakatchewan, conferred on you an honorary doctorate in 2016 in recognition of your contributions to the development story of Asia. After retiring from the ADB, youâve served on multiple boards. Youâre part of a policy based think tank network in Washington D.C. where you a Distinighished Fellow as well at a similar institute in China. You also serve as the President of the Action for Autism Network in India. And for our audience, of course, you are also a board member at the Advanced Study Institute of Asia and a Distinguished Fellow here at ASIA.
With that introduction, I want to begin the conversation proper. As always on SenseMaker, weâre exploring a thematic issue. This edition of Decypher is centred around âPower.â So my first question is simple:
Are we in the twilight of institutions? Have we reached a point where institutions are at the mercy of individual power, rather than the other way around?
Rajat Nag:
Well, the short answer is no. We are certainly not in the twilight of institutions. If anything, institutions are more needed now than ever before. I do understand where youâre coming from institutions are indeed under threat, and in many places under attack. But thatâs exactly why they matter more. Societies cannot survive without institutions. They may evolve, take different forms, but I do not see us moving away from the need for strong, robust institutional frameworks.
Amogh Dev Rai:
Thatâs interesting. Many of our readers will be aware of your contribution to this debate through your recent book From Here to Denmark, where you analyse institutional evolution across countries. One of the standout aspects of that book is how it combines analytical depth with grounded case studiesâsomething not easy to do.
So as a follow-up can you walk us through some of the institutional stories youâve studied? You allude to future generations in your answer, but Iâm curious about what trajectories youâve found across countries youâve examined.
Rajat Nag:
Before diving into specific countries, let me step back briefly. At its core, the institutional story is about two things. First, institutions are the ârules of the gameâârules that societies evolve over time, giving a framework for how social interactions and governance happen. Second, and just as important, is enforcement. Rules without enforcement are mere words. Institutions only hold if both the rules and enforcement mechanisms exist and reinforce each other.
When we studied different societiesâwhether Denmark and Great Britain in Europe, Japan and Korea in Asia, Botswana in Africa, or Uruguay in Latin Americaâwe saw a common thread. Despite different cultural and historical contexts, all these societies developed institutions by gradually building consensus around rules of engagement and their enforcement. This mutual reinforcement is key. You canât have one without the other.
Now, depending on the structure of society, institutions evolve differently. Broadly, we see two societal structures: limited access orders and open access orders.
Amogh Dev Rai:
Could you expand on that distinction a bit?
Rajat Nag:
Certainly. In limited access orders, elites control the levers of power. They write the rules to serve their interests and enforce them to maintain their dominance. This leads to extractive, exclusionary institutions designed to preserve the power of a few at the expense of the many.
On the other hand, open access orders are based on merit, competition, and fairness. Entry and rewards are not determined by oneâs birth or family connections, but by oneâs ability and performance. Rules in such societies are clear and enforced uniformly.
So, for any society to achieve good governance, it must make the transition from a limited to an open access order. It doesnât happen overnight. It can take decades or even centuries. But thatâs the trajectory. Despite different paths societies may follow to reach their âDenmarksâ , the goal remains the sameâopen, inclusive institutions that uphold fairness.
Amogh Dev Rai:
Iâve always admired the breadth of countries you coverâyou donât confine yourself to GDP per capita or the usual development yardsticks economists often prefer. But thereâs something Iâve been meaning to ask you againâbecause it puzzled me the first time we spoke about it.
What happens when institutions, having reached their apex, begin to turn inward or decline? Weâve seen this in the United States and other places. Thereâs been a shift away from accountability, something you stress in your work as essential for institutional legitimacy.
In the US, people rally around â1776â as a kind of nostalgic war cry but they forget how long it actually took to build institutions that worked for everyone. Why do societies that have benefited the most from institutional strength seem to turn away from them?
Rajat Nag:
Let me try and break that down in two parts. First, the idea that institutions, once established, are somehow permanentâthatâs an idle thought. Institutions, even the most robust ones, are fragile. They need constant nurturing. Theyâre not monuments; theyâre living organisms.
The context in which institutions emerge is never static. The social norms, cultural values, economic conditionsâall of these change. So, institutions must evolve too. What worked in 1776 canât simply be carried over into 2025 without adaptation. Otherwise, they become irrelevant.
Now, the second part of your question: why do people start turning inward or away from institutions? Thatâs about power. Remember, institutions are essentially frameworks for distributing and exercising power. But the people enforcing the rules are themselves part of that power structure. When that balance breaks downâwhen enforcement becomes ad hoc or self-servingâpeople lose trust. And when that happens, they retreat. First into themselves, then into smaller identities: family, community, tribe.
The global layer complicates this further. People are now impacted not just by domestic changes but by international economic shifts globalisation, supply chains, outsourcing. You could lose your job not because of anything local, but because someone across the world can do it cheaper. When institutions donât respond to this dislocation, people feel abandoned. That breeds resentment and fuels populist narratives.
Amogh Dev Rai:
And that sets the stage for my next question. In a recent speech at the India International Centre, you made a compelling point: that institutions require constant human engagement. They need flexibility, yes, but also decision-makers who see their human dimension.
So I want to focus on the relationship between institutions and economic shocks. How have economic shifts crises, growth spurts, collapses shaped institutional change in the countries youâve studied? And what must we watch out for going forward?
Rajat Nag:
Thatâs an important question. Economic growth, of course, matters. But what really drives institutional stability is a broader sense of fairness. People donât expect equality of outcome, but they do expect equity, they expect to be trated fairly. They expect fair access to opportunity and a fair share of the gains economic growth creates.
Growth without equity breeds frustration. Globalisation, for instance, has dramatically benfitted the world. Global poverty has come down significantly over the past several decades. People all over the world are richer, live longer and are more educated than they were a generation back. But not everyone has benefitted equally.
Take the Rust Belt in the United States. Workers there lost jobs, not because of personal failings, but because steel manufacturing moved elsewhere, to China mainly. The US car industry and others benefitted significantly from the cheaper steel. China benefitted from exporting the steel . The benefits were widely dispersed, but the costs were concentrated. but the steel workers in the US lost.
When this happens and society fails to recognise or compensate the losers, people lose faith in institutions. Thatâs when institutions come under pressure, not because theyâre inherently flawed, but because theyâre perceived as indifferent to suffering.
So, when institutions fail to mitigate or even acknowledge these lossesâwhen they donât respond to the distress caused by dislocations like job loss, technological change, or globalisationâpeople begin to feel betrayed. They feel the system is rigged. And that opens the door to populism, resentment, and retreat from institutional trust.
Amogh Dev Rai:
Which brings us to a very paradoxical situation. As you said, globalisation has enlarged the pie. Today, weâre not just talking about millionaires and billionairesâweâre inching toward trillionaires. Yet, the backlash against the very institutions that facilitated this growth is strongest in the places that gained the most.
You mentioned fairness earlier. But how do we explain the fact that leaders like Viktor OrbĂĄn in Hungary or Donald Trump in the USâwho belong to the very structures that benefited from institutionsâare now attacking them? Whatâs really driving this anti-institutional fervour from the top?
Rajat Nag:
Itâs a crucial question. Again, it ties back to inequality. Globalisation has done a lot of good economic, social, even cultural. But the perception of being left behind is a powerful one, and often itâs not totally misplaced.
Steel workers who lose their jobs in the US rust belt see their lives stagnating. Their social standing erodes. A job is not just a paycheque itâs also a marker of dignity, relevance, and purpose. When thatâs taken away, it breeds anger. And that anger can be harnessed by political forces.
Along comes a populist leader who says, âItâs not your fault. The elites, the global âItâs not your fault. The elites, the global institutions, the immigrants, the foreign trade pactsâtheyâre to blame. But Iâll fix it.â This narrative has enormous emotional appeal. Itâs simple. It offers a target. And it claims to restore dignity.
The tragedy is that the institutions being blamedâmultilateral bodies, trade systems, even democratic processesâare in many cases what held things together for decades. But theyâre not perfect. And when they donât adapt fast enough, they become easy scapegoats.
Amogh Dev Rai:
And you know this better than most, having spent decades at the helm of a multilateral institution like the ADB. Letâs talk about that a bit more directly. These institutions carry enormous power, but theyâre also constantly under pressure sometimes fairly, often unfairly.
You were managing director general during the 2008 financial crisis arguably the most serious economic shock in recent memory. So, Iâd like to ask in two parts.
First, how do these institutions actually make decisions? From the outside, they often seem like black boxesâinsular, opaque, elitist. Itâs easy for critics to say theyâre run by a few for the few. Is that true?
Rajat Nag:
Thatâs a fair question. So, letâs clarify how these institutions are structured. Take the Asian Development Bank, or the World Bank. Unlike the United Nations where each country has one vote, voting power in these multilateral development institutions is weighted by their shareholding.
This obviously means that developed countries have more say in decision-making. Thatâs just a structural reality. But I must add that most decisions are taken by consensus.
Now, the critique that these institutions are black boxes itâs not baseless. Thereâs complexity, yes. But they do engage extensively with civil society and other stakeholers. Itâs part of the operational process. However, letâs be clear: the loans or assistance ultimately go to sovereign governments. NGOs or citizens may offer inputs, but final decisions lie with the state.
So yes, civil society voices are heard. But no, they do not carry the same weight as that of member states, especially the more powerful ones.
Amogh Dev Rai:
That brings me to the second part of the question. Many of us, especially those trained in economics after 2008, have felt that the discipline had lost its moral compass. Thereâs been a drift towards mathematical abstraction, sometimes called âphysics envy,â where models trump common sense. This has affected institutional policy-making too.
Take the United Kingdom. In your book, you mention its institutional transformation as an example of resilience. But economically, itâs been trapped in austerity for more than a decade. Despite promises of reform, there seems to be no exit from this self-imposed straitjacket.
Why donât bad policies have expiry dates? Why canât institutions say, âThis isnât working anymore. Letâs stop.â Why do we return to outdated metrics like GDP growth, as if theyâre sacrosanct?
Rajat Nag:
Good point. Yes, GDP is important, but woefully insufficient. The fixation with GDP as the sole metric of progress fails to recognise important issues such as inequality, social deprivations, health, education, climate change etc.
Now, austerity as an economic policy emerged from Keynesian thoughtâspend during crises, save during booms. But what happened in many countries was that governments didnât save during good times. When things got bad, there were no buffers left. So they were pushed into cutting spending at the worst possible moment.
Now, in theory, yes, multilateral institutions could push back. But they are constrained. They advise fiscal discipline, yes, but they donât control political choices which are made and must be made by sovereign states.
Rajat Nag:
To me, the deeper issue isnât just about austerity or GDPâitâs about the responsiveness of economic policy. Policies often continue not because they are still appropriate , but because changing them is politically difficult. And institutions, even multilateral ones, often lack the agility or the courage to declare when a policy has outlived its usefulness.
The 2008 crisis, for example, was largely a failure of due diligence in financial markets. Lending had become untethered from accountability. Banks were pushing loans not based on repayment capacity, but on short-term margins. Once the bubble burst, the entire system collapsed like dominoes.
So, yes, institutional reform is about structure but itâs also about moral clarity. You need both economics and ethics. Thatâs what gets lost when policy becomes overly politcised in the wrong hands.
Amogh Dev Rai:
Letâs now move to the final segment of our conversationâyour three-pillar framework. Youâve written that the state, the market, and the community must work in tandem for institutions to thrive. Could you walk us through that model?
Rajat Nag:
Absolutely. Think of society as a tripod. One leg is the stateâresponsible for governance and justice. The second is the marketâdriving innovation, efficiency, and production. The third is the community or civil societyâwhere norms, values, and accountability are rooted.
These three need to co-exist, but more importantly, they need to balance each other. You donât want a Leviathan state that crushes liberty. You donât want unfettered markets dominated by monopolies or ârobber barons.â And you donât want a fragmented civil society, which descends into chaos or vigilante justice. Each pillar can go astray if left unchecked.
So the key is balance. When one pillar overreaches, the others must push back, and counterbalance. Thatâs how you keep institutions supple, responsive, and grounded.
Amogh Dev Rai:
But hereâs a harder questionâhow do you make that work in the Global South, where democracy was overlaid after colonialism, rather than emerging organically? Western experts often fly in with checklists. Yet, even Sudan had elections. The forms of democracy donât always produce democratic outcomes.
At the same time, countries like China argue they have functioning institutionsâeven if they donât fit Western models. So whereâs the sweet spot? How should developing nations evolve?
Rajat Nag:
Very important question. The answer, in my view, lies in participation not labels. Call it democracy, call it something else but ask: do people have a voice in decisions that affect them? Is there transparency? Is there accountability?
Mechanisms must reflect local contexts. The principle of subsidiarity is keyâtake decisions at the lowest possible level of accountability. Indiaâs Panchayati system is a good example, despite its flaws. Copy-pasting institutions from elsewhere doesnât work. They must grow from within.
Amogh Dev Rai:
That connects to the trust deficitâanother theme running through this conversation.
Do you think the erosion of trust in these three pillars is whatâs ultimately crippling democracies?
Rajat Nag:
Without a doubt. When the three travellersâstate, market, societyâstop trusting one another, cooperation collapses. Transparency fades. Cynicism takes root.
Sometimes, this mistrust is deeply historical. There are studies showing that in areas affected by the transatlantic slave trade, mistrust remains high even todayâpassed down generations. When people feel betrayed by institutions or leaders, they default to suspicion. And once trust erodes, rebuilding it is an uphill battle.
Amogh Dev Rai:
Which brings me to my penultimate questionâhow can nations today simultaneously plan for prosperity and security? Especially given the chaos around us, the breakdown of regional trust, and the erosion of multilateralism?
Rajat Nag:
We need to define security more broadly. Itâs not just freedom from external threatâitâs freedom from fear. Fear of the police. Fear of the state. Fear of the feudal landlords. Fear of speaking up.
That kind of securityâfreedom from fear and injusticeâis the foundation for prosperity. If people feel secure in the broadest sense, investment will follow. Growth will follow.
And that feeling of security comes from robust and inclusive institutions. From good governance. From predictable laws. From justice that is seen to be done.
Amogh Dev Rai:
Final question. Are you hopeful?
Rajat Nag:
I am. History teaches us that humans are resilient. Weâve survived wars, famines, financial collapses.
Institutions will evolve. Societies will adapt. The human species has always found a way to walk back from the brink. I believe we will again.
Amogh Dev Rai:
I sincerely hope youâre right. Thank you so much for your time, and for this wide-ranging conversation.
Rajat Nag:
Thank you.
The link has been copied!